
Dynamic Money-in-Utility Model
Document information
Author | Dina Antipina |
instructor | Antti Ripatti, Professor |
School | University of Helsinki |
Major | Economics |
Document type | Master’s Thesis |
Language | English |
Format | |
Size | 1.06 MB |
Summary
I.Literature Review of Money Demand Theories
This section reviews prominent money demand theories, tracing their evolution from the classical equation of exchange (Irving Fisher) and the Cambridge approach (Pigou, Marshall) to the contributions of Keynes. Keynesian theory introduced the concepts of transaction, precautionary, and speculative motives for holding money. Post-Keynesian developments further refined these ideas, incorporating models like the Baumol-Tobin model (transactions costs) and the Miller-Orr model (cash management under uncertainty). The review also covers the cash-in-advance (CIA) model, shopping-time models, and search-theoretic models of money, highlighting their strengths and weaknesses in explaining the role of money in the economy. The Money-in-the-Utility-Function (MIUF) model, central to the main analysis, is introduced as a versatile framework for studying monetary economics and monetary policy effects.
1. Classical and Neoclassical Foundations
The review begins by examining the classical foundations of money demand theory, starting with Irving Fisher's equation of exchange. This approach, central to the quantity theory of money, posits a direct relationship between the money supply and the price level, assuming a constant velocity of money circulation and a fixed volume of transactions. The limitations of this approach, especially the assumption of constant velocity, are highlighted. The Cambridge approach, associated with Pigou and Marshall, offers an alternative within the quantity theory framework. This perspective shifts the focus from money supply to money demand, exploring the factors that influence individuals' preferences for holding money balances. Unlike Fisher's approach, the Cambridge approach emphasizes the individual's choice-making behavior and the determinants of their desired cash balances, enriching the understanding of money demand dynamics.
2. Keynesian and Post Keynesian Perspectives
The review then delves into Keynesian contributions to money demand theory. Keynes significantly expanded the understanding of money demand by introducing multiple motives for holding money: transactions, precautionary, and speculative motives. The transactions motive relates to the need for money to facilitate everyday transactions, while the precautionary motive reflects the desire to hold money for unforeseen expenses. The speculative motive, a key innovation, highlights the role of uncertainty about future interest rates in shaping individuals' portfolio choices between money and bonds. Keynes's analysis also demonstrated how, under conditions of very low interest rates, aggregate money demand can become perfectly elastic, leading to a liquidity trap where monetary policy becomes ineffective. Post-Keynesian developments are then explored, acknowledging that Keynes's analysis doesn't directly translate individual behavior into aggregate economy dynamics, and building upon Keynes' foundational work by focusing on a more nuanced understanding of the various motives for holding money, especially the role of the interest rate in influencing money demand.
3. Specific Models of Money Demand
This section summarizes several prominent models of money demand. The Baumol-Tobin (B-T) model introduces the concept of transactions costs as a key determinant of money demand, demonstrating the trade-off between the liquidity services of money and the opportunity cost of holding non-interest-bearing assets. The Miller-Orr model analyzes cash management under uncertainty, emphasizing the optimal cash balance levels for firms facing stochastic cash flows and fixed transaction costs. In contrast to these models, the section discusses the Cash-in-Advance (CIA) model, which emphasizes money's role as a medium of exchange by imposing a constraint where purchases must be financed with money held in advance. The limitations of this rigid assumption are acknowledged, and the shopping-time model is also discussed as another approach to incorporating money's medium of exchange function, focusing on the trade-off between time spent shopping and leisure.
4. The Money in the Utility Function MIUF Approach
The literature review concludes by focusing on the Money-in-the-Utility-Function (MIUF) approach, introduced by Sidrauski (1967). This approach directly incorporates money balances into the household's utility function, recognizing that households derive utility from holding money. The MIUF model provides a comprehensive framework for investigating interactions in monetary economics, examining relationships between money, prices, inflation, and the impacts of monetary policy. The flexibility and wide applicability of the MIUF model, encompassing models from cash-in-advance to capital asset pricing models, are highlighted, emphasizing its importance as a general framework for analyzing various monetary phenomena. This approach is presented as a foundation for the model used in the main body of the research, showcasing its significance in understanding the complexities of money demand and its implications for macroeconomic analysis.
II.A Dynamic MIUF Model with Monetary and Technology Shocks
The core of the research presents a novel dynamic macroeconomic model employing the MIUF approach. This model features two representative agents—a household and a firm—interacting within a flexible-price environment. A key feature is the use of a non-separable utility function, leading to non-neutrality of money. The model is solved using log-linearization around the steady state, generating a system of linear equations. The analysis focuses on the impact of exogenous monetary shocks and technology shocks on economic equilibrium, using impulse response functions to visualize the dynamic effects. The model's solution employs the method of undetermined coefficients to solve linear difference expectation equations. The crucial aspect of the non-separable utility function allows for a direct investigation of the impact of variations in real money balances on the equilibrium level of consumption and labor supply, deviating from the neutrality of money observed in models with separable utility functions.
1. Model Structure and Methodology
The research employs a dynamic Money-in-the-Utility-Function (MIUF) framework to investigate the economy's response to monetary and technology shocks. A key feature is the incorporation of a non-separable utility function, a departure from standard models, implying the non-neutrality of real money balances. The model uses a simplified structure with two representative agents: a household and a firm, each maximizing their respective utility and profit functions subject to budget constraints. To solve the resulting complex non-linear equations, the researchers employ a log-linearization technique around the steady state, transforming the system into a set of tractable linear equations. This allows for a detailed analysis of the equilibrium responses to shocks using the method of undetermined coefficients to solve a system of linear difference expectation equations. The analysis is complemented by the presentation of Impulse Response Functions (IRFs), providing a visual representation of the dynamic effects of the shocks on key economic variables.
2. Model Components Agents and Constraints
The model's foundation lies in the interaction of a representative household and a representative firm. The household's behavior is determined by its utility maximization problem, subject to a budget constraint that incorporates consumption, investment in assets (bonds), holdings of money balances (with an associated opportunity cost), labor income, and taxes/transfers. The firm’s behavior is driven by profit maximization, taking into account production technology and input costs. The interaction of these agents within the model determines the dynamic equilibrium of the economy, with the equilibrium being reached when the optimal paths of both agents coincide, given market prices. The non-separability of the utility function plays a crucial role, as it links the marginal utility of consumption directly to variations in real money balances, influencing the model's response to monetary policy. This feature differs significantly from standard models with separable utility, where monetary policy generally has no impact on real variables.
3. Analysis of Monetary Shocks
The study analyzes the effects of unanticipated and anticipated monetary shocks on the model's equilibrium. The response depends significantly on the persistence of the shock (represented by the autoregressive coefficient ρθ). When the autoregressive coefficient is zero (ρ θ = 0), the impact is limited to a one-period effect, altering only the level of real money balances. However, when ρθ > 0, monetary shocks exhibit positive autocorrelation, which influence the money growth rate and impact economic activity more significantly over time. A positive monetary shock increases expected inflation, acting as a tax on real money balances. The model shows how these shocks can lead to changes in nominal interest rates, inflation, output, and employment. Crucially, the relative magnitudes of the liquidity effect (lower interest rate, higher output) and the anticipated inflation effect (higher interest rate, lower output) are analyzed, with the results demonstrating the anticipated inflation effect dominates in this particular model setup. This dominance is linked to the chosen parameter values and their effects on the key variables of the model.
4. Analysis of Technology Shocks and Comparison to RBC Theory
The model also investigates the effects of technology shocks, comparing the results with predictions from Real Business Cycle (RBC) theory. Unlike the standard RBC model, which generally predicts an increase in labor supply and output in response to a positive technology shock, the model presented yields counter-intuitive results: labor input declines following a technology shock. These findings are discussed in light of previous empirical studies (Galí 1999, Shea 1998, Basu, Fernald, and Kimball 1999, Francis and Ramey 2001), which support the notion that technology shocks can lead to a reduction in labor input. The contrasting predictions of the model and the standard RBC theory highlight the importance of model specification and parameter choices in determining the impact of technology shocks on macroeconomic variables, prompting a discussion about potential refinements to standard RBC theory to account for these findings. This contrast creates a point of discussion for alternative explanations of business cycle fluctuations.
III.Model Analysis and Results Monetary Shocks
The analysis of monetary shocks reveals that the model's predictions depend critically on the autoregressive coefficient (ρθ) which determines the persistence of the shock. The results show the interplay between the liquidity effect (a drop in the nominal interest rate and rise in output) and the anticipated inflation effect (increase in the nominal interest rate and decline in output). The findings suggest that in this model, the anticipated inflation effect dominates the liquidity effect, an outcome influenced by the chosen parameter values and their impact on the marginal utility of consumption and labor supply. The model shows how changes in the money supply can affect key macroeconomic variables such as inflation, output, and employment.
1. Impact of Monetary Shocks Persistence and Autocorrelation
The analysis of monetary shocks within the model reveals a crucial dependence on the autoregressive coefficient (ρ θ), which governs the persistence of the shock. When ρ θ is set to zero, indicating no autocorrelation, an unanticipated monetary shock has only a one-period impact, primarily affecting the level of real money balances. The price level adjusts proportionally to the shock, leaving other economic variables unaffected. However, when ρ θ > 0, introducing positive autocorrelation, the monetary shock's influence extends beyond a single period. A positive monetary shock results in a money growth rate exceeding the average, leading agents to anticipate similar effects in the future. This anticipation fuels an increase in expected inflation, creating a dynamic feedback loop where anticipated inflation begins to work as a 'tax' on real money balances, impacting multiple aspects of the economic equilibrium.
2. Liquidity Effect vs. Anticipated Inflation Effect
The model demonstrates the interplay between two countervailing effects of a positive monetary shock: the liquidity effect and the anticipated inflation effect. The liquidity effect is characterized by a decrease in the nominal interest rate, stimulating an increase in output. Conversely, the anticipated inflation effect features a rise in the nominal interest rate, leading to a decline in output. The model's results show that the anticipated inflation effect dominates the liquidity effect. This dominance isn't merely a coincidence; it's directly linked to the value of the autoregressive coefficient (ρ θ). This parameter determines the autocorrelation of the monetary shock and its persistence, directly influencing the strength of the anticipated inflation effect relative to the liquidity effect. Therefore, the relative magnitudes of these two counteracting forces are dependent on the degree of persistence of the monetary shock which influences the anticipation of future inflation.
3. Model Parameters and Results Interpretation
The numerical results obtained depend heavily on the choice of parameter values. Specific parameter values (σ = 2, ν = 2.56, η = 4, ρ θ = 0.5, β = 1, ϕ = 1, km ≈ 0.3) are chosen for the analysis, consistent with existing literature (Galí 2008, Cooley and Hansen 1989). These choices shape the model's quantitative predictions. For example, the negative sign of Λ θ indicates that a positive monetary shock increases inflation and the nominal interest rate but decreases aggregate demand, real money demand, equilibrium output, and employment. The choice of a non-separable utility function (σ ≠ ν) and a specific autoregressive parameter (ρ θ) are highlighted as key features shaping these outcomes. The resulting dynamic responses are a consequence of the interplay between the chosen parameters, the model's structure, and the inherent properties of the non-separable utility function.
IV.Model Analysis and Results Technology Shocks
The analysis of technology shocks, which is considered in this model, investigates its impact on the economy, specifically comparing the predictions of the model against the findings of the Real Business Cycle (RBC) theory. The results of the technology shock analysis are shown to differ from the standard RBC theory predictions, where positive technology shocks typically lead to increased labor supply and output. In this model, these findings provide interesting counterpoints to the classical RBC theory predictions, raising questions about the driving forces behind business cycle fluctuations and prompting discussions on potentially modifying the RBC framework to account for these empirical observations.
1. Contrasting Model Predictions with RBC Theory
The analysis of technology shocks reveals results that deviate from the standard predictions of Real Business Cycle (RBC) theory. RBC theory, pioneered by Kydland and Prescott (1982) and Long and Plosser (1983), posits that technology shocks are a primary driver of economic fluctuations, leading to increased labor supply and output as households respond to higher productivity. However, the model presented here produces contrasting results: a positive technology shock leads to a decline in labor input. This counter-intuitive finding is discussed in the context of influential empirical studies that also show technology shocks causing a decline in labor, questioning the standard RBC narrative and suggesting a need for refinements to existing theoretical frameworks.
2. Empirical Evidence and Theoretical Implications
The discrepancy between the model's predictions and the standard RBC theory is supported by referencing empirical evidence from several key papers. Galí (1999), Shea (1998), and Basu, Fernald, and Kimball (1999) all find that technology shocks lead to a reduction in labor input, and Francis and Ramey (2001) confirm this result. These findings, if considered robust, raise fundamental questions about the validity of the basic RBC theory as a comprehensive explanation of business cycle fluctuations. The model's results suggest that a simple adjustment to the standard RBC framework might not fully capture the complexities of the relationship between technology shocks and labor market responses. This creates an opening for discussion on alternative or extended models that better represent real-world dynamics.
3. Potential Explanations and Further Research
The model's findings of a negative labor supply response to technology shocks suggest a potential shift in focus away from pure supply-side explanations of economic fluctuations. The results could be interpreted as indicating a scenario where, in response to a technology shock, the demand-side effects outweigh the supply-side effects. This could lead to a situation where increased productivity doesn't automatically translate into increased labor demand, potentially due to factors not explicitly included in the standard RBC model. The paper ends by posing a question: should this discrepancy be viewed as evidence against the existing RBC framework, or should the framework itself be altered to accommodate these new empirical observations? The analysis of technology shocks, therefore, provides a crucial counterpoint to established macroeconomic theories, highlighting the need for further research and potentially leading to important modifications and revisions in our understanding of business cycle dynamics.
V.Conclusion
This study provides a framework for analyzing the effects of both monetary policy (through monetary shocks) and technology shocks on economic equilibrium, using a dynamic MIUF model with a non-separable utility function. The findings highlight the importance of considering the interplay between liquidity and anticipated inflation effects in response to monetary shocks, and offer insights that contrast with the predictions of the standard RBC model concerning technology shocks. Further research could explore alternative parameterizations and extensions of the model to deepen the understanding of these complex interactions.
1. Summary of Findings on Economic Agent Interactions and Shocks
The study investigated the interactions of economic agents, the resulting equilibrium, and the impact of exogenous monetary and technology shocks on this equilibrium. A key finding was the model's ability to analyze how these shocks affected the economic equilibrium, demonstrating the model's usefulness in understanding the complex interplay between agents and external forces. The research highlights money supply as a pivotal element in monetary policy modeling, emphasizing monetary policy's crucial role within macroeconomic models that analyze monetary issues. The study also showed that technology shocks, introducing random variations in productivity, can cause fluctuations in the economy's constant trend, underscoring the significance of studying both monetary and real-side shocks in understanding macroeconomic dynamics. The findings, therefore, showcase a model capable of capturing important interactions and their responses to critical economic shocks.
2. Model Implications and Future Research Directions
The constructed model, using a dynamic Money-in-the-Utility-Function (MIUF) framework with a non-separable utility function, provides a valuable tool for analyzing the complex interactions of economic agents and their responses to shocks. The results of the model challenge aspects of the standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) theory's predictions on the effects of technology shocks, presenting a starting point for further investigation. The emphasis is on furthering our understanding of the ways in which monetary and technology shocks interact with agents' behavior to impact economic equilibrium. Future research could extend the model to incorporate additional factors or alternative specifications, potentially offering further insights into the dynamics under consideration. The model presented is a valuable contribution, highlighting the importance of modeling details (such as the type of utility function and the autocorrelation of shocks) and encouraging further study into the dynamic interactions between economic agents and external economic forces.